?

Log in

No account? Create an account
A Bland and Deadly Courtesy
 
[Most Recent Entries] [Calendar View] [Friends View]

Tuesday, November 17th, 2009

Time Event
9:31p
TWoN Book 2 Chapter 4

This chapter deals with the particular characteristics of stock (capital) when it is lent at interest.  He spends some time explaining why it should be lent to those who will invest it in productive ventures, rather than to those who will spend it; but this part doesn’t interest me a great deal.

On page 292 he says, “Almost all loans at interest are made in money, either of paper, or of gold and silver.  But what the borrower really wants, and what the lender really supplies him with, is not the money, but the money’s worth, or the goods which it can purchase…By means of the loan, the lender, as it were, assigns to the borrower his right to a certain portion of the annual produce of the land and labor of the country, to be employed as the borrower pleases.”

The point being that the amount of money that can be loaned is not determined by the value of the money, but “by the value of that part of the annual produce which, as soon as it comes either from the ground, or from the hands of the productive laborers, is destined not only for replacing a capital, but such a capital as the owner does not care to be at the trouble of employing himself.”  What strikes me about this is that, in some ways, the limiting factor becomes the resources of the lender (usually expressed in interest), but the controlling factor is the use the borrower wishes to make of it.  This is especially interesting when we consider the latter stages of capitalism, when finance capital assumes control over industrial capital.

He then goes on to discuss how certain money might be used several times, being lent, spent, lent again, spent again, and so on among different lenders and borrowers.  This seems to be intended to reinforce his earlier point about why money cannot be counted as part of nation’s wealth.

On page 294 we find: “The increase of those particular capitals from which the owners wish to derive a revenue, without being at the trouble of employing them themselves, naturally accompanies the general increase of capitals; or, in other words, as stock increases, the quantity of stock to be lent at interest grows gradually greater and greater.”   And then, further down, “As capitals increase, in any country, the profits which can be made by employing them necessarily diminish.”  These points are significant as yet another reason why capitalism, as a system, must constantly expand.  Indeed, someone could make an argument that Adam Smith predicted the World Wars without stretching the truth too awfully much.

Page 296: “Any increase in the quantity of silver, while that of the commodities circulated by means of it remained the same, could have no other effect than to diminish the value of that metal.  The nominal value of all sorts of goods would be greater, but their real value would be precisely the same as before.”   Very true.  The value of a commodity consists in the amount of labor embodied in it, and this labor may be expressed as gold, silver, paper, or in terms of other commodities.   “The wages of labor are commonly computed tye quantity of gold and silver which is paid to the laborer.  When that is increased, therefore, his wages appear to be increased, though they may sometimes be no greater than before.  But the profits of stock are not computed by the number of pieces of silver with which they are paid, but by the proportion which those pieces bear to the whole capital employed.”

He then goes on to discuss the relationship between the interest of money and the profits of stock (ie, loan rates are closely tied to return on investment from agriculture or manufacture).

It is interesting to note, at the bottom of page 298, that Smith is in favor of having a legal limit to interest rates.  He proposes that this limit be just a little above the lowest market rate.  Smith could not have predicted the volatility of the money markets; with interest rates fluctuated as they do today, such a plan is impractical.  But it is interesting that Smith proposes it.

Page 299: “No law can reduce the common rate of interest below the lowest ordinary market rate at the time when that law is made.”  Because money, being a commodity like any other, has its price (expressed, like anything else, in terms of labor), and if the law requires a rate below its cost, no one will lend it, or else they will circumvent the law (which, by increasing the risk, will increase the cost).

Still on 299, this is very interesting: “The ordinary market price of land, it is to be observed, depends everywhere upon the ordinary market rate of interest.”  Is that still true?  If so, why?  Much of this feels like a relic of the past–that is, at the time Smith was writing, we were just emerging from a feudal monarchical system where land (ownership and production) formed the entire basis of the economy; he was poised on the brink, as it were, of an economy based on commodity production.  I think this explains why he sees such importance in land.  Not long afterward, the question became: lend money at interest, or invest in manufacture?  But at the end of the 18th century, we still aren’t quite there.

Originally published at Words Words Words. Please leave any comments there.

<< Previous Day 2009/11/17
[Calendar]
Next Day >>
The Dream Cafe   About LiveJournal.com